Category Archives: political parties

Political Parties—New Ideas

As I mentioned in my last post on this topic, we have a political party that was elected in part because Americans are concerned about the price of groceries. Now that they hold three branches of government, their primary budget goal is to maintain and extend tax breaks that overwhelmingly benefit the very wealthiest in our society. And to pay for it, they are targeting food assistance, subsidies to health care through Medicaid and Medicare, and now Social Security.

As promised, here is the core of a new idea about how to think about rebuilding our party system. Again, this is a slight re-edit from an article I wrote almost a decade ago:

Wed to responsible party government and conceiving of parties narrowly and almost exclusively as ideological speakers, party reformers have been blind to the democratic potential arising out of the associational diversity within the partisan network. This blindness has prevented systematic consideration of both the part association can play in mobilizing and informing citizens and the ways that building out the associational life of contemporary political parties–by shoring up those nodes of the partisan network capable of fostering social ties between elected officials and activists and between activists and constituents–could contribute to good governance.

Contemporary party organizations, while not the membership organizations of bygone eras, have yet to shed their essential associational attributes. The era of nineteenth-century urban machine politics that depended on the confluence of relatively strong personal ties and a formal organization bound by patronage is long gone. Yet, even in the twenty-first century, political parties remain networks of individuals and groups– activists, donors, officeholders, and dealmakers–tied together and to the electorate by social connections of various strengths. Beyond their capacity to act as vehicles for aggregating and amplifying preferences and perspectives, the formal parties have an associational life, although there is great variation in the depth and breadth of that life.

Although some of this has changed since 2020 (particularly who votes), those concerned about the Democratic Party’s losses still have something to learn from this diagnosis:

. . . Without denying that the causes of our crisis in representation are numerous, an associational path to responsible party governance takes as its starting point a significantly underappreciated transformation of the political landscape: the increasing social isolation of political elites and its impact on both participation and the flow of political information between ordinary Americans and their leaders.

The contrast between the social networks of political elites today and those in prior eras of American history is both stark and revealing. While democratic politics is frequently a contest among elites, prior to the advent of mass media, candidates needed “to build extensive interpersonal networks not confined to particular occupational or social circles” to garner reputation and votes. As such, the path to political power ran through membership in socioeconomically integrated civic associations–the Shriners, the Rotary Club, the American Legion. These groups required regular attendance at meetings and frequently involved election to higher offices and attendance at federated meetings. Political elites were thereby prevented from becoming socially insulated from the rest of American society.

By contrast, electoral incentives today pull candidates and parties into a narrow social network of extremely unrepresentative and socially isolated donors and activists. Given the sheer cost of running a federal campaign in the current era, individuals running for office are required to tap their social networks for significant early capital to gain the confidence of party operatives. It is, thus, not surprising that a vast majority of members of Congress are millionaires.

Even beyond the donor circle, the tendency of contemporary political parties has been to eschew broad mobilization. For the average voter, computer-generated requests for donations have replaced the ward boss as the personal face of the party. This is particularly concerning since those most likely to be targeted by such impersonal requests also happen to have relatively high incomes and levels of educational attainment. Political commentator Michael Lind only slightly overstates the case when he writes:

Politicians chosen by membership-based mass parties have been replaced by politicians selected by donors and sold … to voters. At the same time, the decline of neighborhood party machines turning out the vote has resulted in declining participation by lower income and less educated voters. The Americans who do vote are disproportionately affluent.

When millionaires constitute a supermajority of Congress and lawyers are overrepresented in Congress, the interests of lawyers, millionaires, and college-educated white men have more resonance than other interests and experiences. The absence of individuals with more typical experiences of American life–individuals who have never had a white-collar professional job, women who have left their young, school-age children at home with siblings because they cannot afford daycare, or those who regularly navigate the criminal justice or welfare systems–in Congress (and presumably in the social networks of the partisans upon whom members of Congress rely for policy advice) makes it significantly less likely that Congress will prioritize policies addressing the experience of such citizens.

To make matters worse, entrenched socioeconomic segregation means politicians– even ones who gain from church attendance or NRA membership–are much more socially isolated from individuals from different walks of life than they were in the past. Put plainly, if members of Congress and their associates were financially dependent on public education for their children, they might not have been quite as taken aback by the broad bipartisan outrage at Betsy DeVos’s nomination. Equally important, the less government addresses those needs, the more likely those constituents will disengage from electoral politics, and the vicious cycle begins. While few would wish to return to the eras in which political power ran through sex-segregated and racially exclusionary clubs–veterans’ groups, Masonic Lodges, or the Klan–the socioeconomic exclusivity of contemporary partisan networks has had democratic costs.

Social insularity of party elites along with the unrepresentativeness of both voters and party activists affects the types of policies and actions that are considered, even in the absence of corruption or undue influence. Individuals’ experiences of the world shape how they process information, what issues they prioritize, and what issues fall off their radars. A behavioral economist might describe this in terms of the availability heuristic; an anthropologist might describe it in terms of culture and social practice. The bottom line, however, is the same: Social context shapes what one prioritizes (e.g., tax cuts or social security), finds reasonable (e.g., accepting extravagant gifts from donors or engaging in an illicit market to make ends meet), and perceives as being problematic (e.g., what constitutes sexual harassment or racism). No amount of data or polling can compensate for the fact that polls are written by the very elites whose world experiences are increasingly insular.

The associational life of partisan elites inevitably affects responsiveness and accountability. The absence of consideration of this phenomenon by responsible party government theorists can probably be attributed to the fact that through the 1950s, elected officials and party leaders had robust ties to their constituents through membership associations based on socioeconomic status (if not race or gender). Churches, veterans’ groups, and even the Ku Klux Klan in the South were extremely well integrated into the party network.

The optimal partisan network, it follows, is one with both socioeconomic and intergenerational breadth and interpersonal depth. Such a political organization would be more capable of mobilizing voters of all ages through a broad cadre of party activists with ties to a representative electorate. It would be better able to disseminate political information during and between elections.

There is much more to say and more that I have said about why the associational path is not only theoretically optimal but also practically possible. It is also increasingly clear to me that the reintroduction of fusion politics at the state and local level could go a long way to rebuilding our party system in an associational vein. But for now, I will stop.

Share this:

Political Parties—A Fresh Look

We have a political party that was elected in part because Americans are concerned about the price of groceries. Now that they hold three branches of government, their primary budget goal is to maintain and extend tax breaks that overwhelmingly benefit the very wealthiest in our society. And to pay for it, they are likely to target food assistance and subsidies to health care through Medicaid and Medicare.

While I truly appreciate this blog, most of what is discussed about parties is the same-old, same-old from political science: increase party competition or reform how candidates are selected to achieve a functioning political market. We have been on this train for decades and it has not worked. It is time for fresh ideas and fresh diagnoses of how we got to where we are. In that vein, I wanted to share an excerpt from an article I wrote almost a decade ago, which I happened to be rereading yesterday, and which seems still fitting for this moment.

The puzzle of how to curb the tendency of elected officials to act out of self-interest or at the behest of special interests has plagued the republic since the Founding. Even as the Founders aspired to a republican form of government in which legislators would govern in the public interest, rather than simply vindicate their constituents’ particularized advantages, they fretted over the potential for elected representatives to act out of self-interest or at the behest of special interests. Throughout the ratification debates, for instance, Anti-Federalists raised concerns that the new Constitution would give rise to “a system in which the people would be effectively excluded from the world of public affairs and in which national leaders, only weakly accountable, would have enormous discretion to make law and policy.”

The Constitution’s primary answer to the threat of unaccountable politicians is periodic elections.  Regular elections, it was thought, would guarantee that representatives remained bound to their constituents. The structural features of separation of powers and federalism would provide “auxiliary precautions.”

The shortcomings of elections as instruments for ensuring responsiveness are well known. Among their myriad limitations as vehicles for producing accountability, one has proven particularly intractable: the quality of political participation. Even in a world of competitive districts in which turnout is high and representative, democratic accountability turns on voters having sufficient information to assess the adequacy of representation. Unfortunately, individuals face significant barriers when it comes to monitoring elected officials, and policy ignorance among voters is much more common than is policy knowledge.

Responsible party government pursued an indirect solution to the pervasiveness of voter ignorance. Presenting voters on election day with a choice between clear ideological brands, it hypothesized, would substitute for actual knowledge. Meanwhile, an interest in winning office would incentivize the production of brands responsive to voter preferences.  As in the economic market, political parties would compete to provide the most desirable good, and accountability would follow.

The shortcut proved to be fool’s gold. Merely consuming the political brands manufactured by party elites has not been enough to produce accountability. Despite the increasingly clear choice voters face, the weight of the evidence confirms the Anti-Federalists’ worst fears. At the national level, our leaders are millionaires, “only weakly accountable” to the people, who leverage their enormous policy discretion largely to the advantage of others like themselves. Donors and ideological partisans have become the target audience for party brands, and concern for the preferences of the general electorate is largely coincidental.

What then would happen if one sought to create a system of political accountability the hard way–by seeking to increase informed political participation? The relationship between electoral participation and democratic accountability is certainly complex. 

More to come soon . . . but for the curious . . .

Individual voters may not be capable of monitoring elected officials to hold them accountable, but the same is not necessarily true for organized voters.  It is no accident that federal policy is highly solicitous of the needs of older Americans; they succeed in asserting their interests because they are more politically active and better organized than most Americans.

. . .

New possibilities arise when one resists the urge to overstate the implications of the data supporting voter ignorance. While voter ignorance is certainly pervasive, it need not preclude a path to political accountability in which informed political participation plays a critical role. That route, however, becomes visible only when one puts social ties and membership organizations back into the picture. A substantial body of empirical work supports the hypothesis that intermediary associations, including political parties, can spur political participation and facilitate a two-way street of communication between elites and ordinary citizens [in ways, I would now add, improve policy responsiveness and accountability.]

This is basically why I have become, over the last decade, more interested in third-party politics at the state and local level, and hence the problem of anti-fusion law.

Share this:

Antebellum fusion

Justin again.  I had the “pleasure” of teaching Timmons v. Twin Cities Area New Party again yesterday.  Timmons was a federal constitutional challenge to “anti-fusion” laws: laws preventing two parties on the ballot from nominating the same candidate (and thereby preventing voters from demonstrating their preference for a candidate on one of two or more party lines).

And I was reminded, again, of two things:

  • The remarkable sloppiness of the Court’s drive-by originalism as a rationale for allowing states to entrench a duopoly.  Whatever your view of the political science, it’s pretty clear that the Court gets Federalist No. 10 (and its warning against faction) exactly 180-degrees backward.
  • The remarkably monochromatic nature of the public’s understanding of electoral options based on deep unfamiliarity not just with other countries’ systems, but our own history.  Fusion ballots are just one example of this, of course.  But even students who think they know a lot about Earl Warren as Chief Justice have no idea that he got both the Republican and Democratic nominations for Governor, or even that that’s a conceptual option.

In the latter vein, there’s a really interesting new paper out by Corey Brooks and Beau Tremitiere in the St. John’s Law Review reviewing how northern antislavery parties used fusion in the 1840s and 1850s to grow what would become the Republican Party.  I’m looking forward to digging in.

Share this:

“The Death of Competition in American Elections”

NYT:

President Trump’s return to Washington has tested the bounds of presidential power and set off alarms among Democrats, historians and legal scholars who are warning that the country’s democratic order is under threat.

But a close review of the 2024 election shows just how undemocratic the country’s legislative bodies already are.

After decades of gerrymandering and political polarization, a vast majority of members of Congress and state legislatures did not face competitive general elections last year.

Instead, they were effectively elected through low-turnout or otherwise meaningless primary contests. Vanishingly few voters cast a ballot in those races, according to a New York Times analysis of more than 9,000 congressional and state legislative primary elections held last year. On average, just 57,000 people voted for politicians in U.S. House primaries who went on to win the general election — a small fraction of the more than 700,000 Americans each of those winners now represents.

Increasingly, members of Congress are not even facing primary challenges. About a third of the current members of the House ran unopposed in their primary. All but 12 of those districts were “safe” seats, meaning 124 House members essentially faced no challenge to their election.

The absence of primaries is even more striking in state legislatures. More than three-quarters of those primary races in 2024 were uncontested, according to voting data from The Associated Press.

Lawmakers who do face primaries are often left beholden to a small number of ideologically aligned, fiercely partisan voters — a group all too willing to drag elected representatives to the fringes and to punish them for compromise with the other side.

Share this:

Wisconsin: “Crawford, Schimel won’t pledge to recuse from cases involving political parties”

Wisconsin Public Radio:

With Wisconsin’s Supreme Court election on track to be the most expensive judiciary election in history, neither candidate has pledged to recuse themselves from hearing cases involving the political parties backing their races.

In an interview with WPR, liberal candidate Susan Crawford said that, much as she will not prejudge cases, she will also not prejudge the parties that bring them.

“I think it really comes down to, what kind of dispute is it? Who’s the other party in the case? What kind of legal issues are they raising? And only then make a decision about whether I could be fair and impartial in such a case or not,” she said at a campaign stop in western Wisconsin on Saturday.

That includes the state Democratic Party, she said, which has donated about $2 million in support of her campaign to date.

In a written statement, her conservative opponent, Brad Schimel, said he will set “personal history aside” when ruling, but he did not respond to questions about recusing from cases involving the Republican Party of Wisconsin.

“Before each case, I search my conscience and decide truthfully whether I can rule objectively. I will hold myself to that same process when I serve on the Wisconsin Supreme Court,” he said.

Schimel has received about $1.7 million from the state GOP….

Share this:

“Georgia Republicans renew push for closed primary elections”

AJC:

Top Georgia Republicans are renewing their push to only let voters who register as party members cast ballots in GOP primaries.It’spart of an attempt to guarantee more ideological purity among the nominees.

The idea to end Georgia’s open primaries, which now allow any voter to choose either party’s ballot, has long failed to gain traction.

But Georgia GOP chair Josh McKoon says it’s time to reopen the debate now that President Donald Trump is back in the White House.

He released the party’s “election integrity priorities” late Tuesday, which is topped by a call for closed party primary elections.

McKoon told Politically Georgia that party stalwarts are clear they want “Republican voters electing the Republican nominees.”

“It is common sense to limit participation in Republican primaries to those voters who declare their allegiance to the Republican Party so our nominees reflect the philosophy of our voters,” he said.

The overhaul faces long odds under the Gold Dome and will be staunchly opposed by more mainstream Republicans who rely on moderate and independent votes to carry swing legislative districts….

Share this:

“‘It’s a very dangerous strategy’: The controversial tactic super PACs used to boost Democrats this year”

This Politico story highlights money spent on third-party candidates thought to boost Democratic chances of victory. 

But I’m genuinely pretty confused by the reporting: there’s a claim that the tactic “was used significantly more this year than in other recent elections, a POLITICO analysis found,” but the way the data are presented in the piece, it’s difficult to follow who spent what on whom, and how that compares to other cycles, and it seems like it includes both spending on third-party candidates and attack ads critiquing Republicans from the right.  And though the piece says that “[b]oth parties have long sought to leverage third-party candidates to help them in their races,” there’s no mention of the amount spent in a similar fashion to help Republican candidates.

Share this:

“How N.C. Republicans Learned to Stop Worrying and Start Loving Early Voting”

The subhead of this story in The Assembly: “GOP lawmakers predicted 25 years ago that Democrats would use early voting to steal elections in North Carolina.  This year, they rallied voters to embrace it to secure victory for Donald Trump.”

As voting populations shift partisan preferences, I suspect we’re in for more stories about partisan shifts of opinion on the merits of particular election procedures.  (And also: a gentle reminder that it’s possible to have views on election procedures that don’t depend on their partisan impact.)

Share this:

Historically tiny House majority

As a result of the fact that California counties have certified their elections (yes, even in Shasta County), the last U.S. House race (CD 13, in the Central Valley) was called.  And as a result of that, there are now a number of reports on the 217-215 split that will be “the smallest House majority in history” or “a historically tiny House majority”  (once Gaetz doesn’t return and two other Members take jobs in the Administration).

UPDATE: the inimitable Richard Winger notes that the 1930 election for the 72d Congress elected 217 Republicans, 217 Democrats, and one member of the Farmer-Labor Party.  And it’s true, a one-vote margin is closer than a two-vote margin.

Share this:

“Will NC Republicans have the votes to override Cooper’s veto of powers-stripping bill?”

The story above was about how well the North Carolina elections process works.  Jury’s still out on the state’s democracy process, though.

This News & Observer piece reviews the legislation tacked on to a Helene relief bill, stripping state executive officials’ powers in Democratic hands that might check the Republican-supermajority legislature.  The legislation was passed largely on party lines, vetoed by the Governor, and now needs every Republican legislator in the state House and Senate in order to override the veto.  The Republican Senate has already moved to override.  But that “largely on party lines” statement is really important: three Republican members of the House voted no as the bill was on its way to passage, and there are a lot of eyes on them as the House sets up an override vote for next week.

Share this: