Category Archives: Uncategorized

ACLU et. al. Amicus Brief Supports Standing in The Election-Law Case to be Argued Next Term

The ACLU, the League of Women Voters, and other groups have filed an amicus brief in support of the standing claim raised by candidate for Congress Michael Bost in Bost v. Illinois State Bd of Elections. Bost is seeking to argue that Illinois is violating federal law by permitting absentee ballots to be counted in federal elections if postmarked by Election Day, even if they are received some number of days after Election Day. In an earlier blog post, I said the Court had been right to take this case, given the importance of the standing issue.

The ACLU argues that Bost should have standing, even though it strongly disagrees with his position on the merits. Interestingly, the ACLU argues that a candidate like Bost should have standing based on the “diversion-of-resources” theory of standing, which organizations (like the ACLU and LWV) frequently rely on for standing. The ACLU does not rest its standing argument on the idea that candidates have “competitive standing” to challenge state election laws.

Here’s an excerpt from the amicus brief explaining why candidates, like Bost, should have standing in contexts like this challenge to Illinois election law:

Equally to the point, it is not merely
Representative Bost’s choice to monitor incoming mail
ballots during the post-Election Day period, as the
court of appeals wrongly suggested. It would be
political malpractice not to do so. Candidates and civic
groups working on elections have to conduct their
work in response to the legal framework governing the
election in question. Electoral regulations, no less
than business regulations, “‘may be likely’ to cause
injuries” to parties other than those who are directly
compelled to action by forcing them to spend resources
and thus incur potential economic harms. Diamond
Alt. Energy, 145 S. Ct. at 2136 (citing AHM, 602 U.S.
at 384). Here, Illinois’s regulation of the mail ballot
process, predictably and as a matter of “commonsense
economic realit[y],” “may cause downstream or
upstream economic injuries” to candidates, voters,
voter registration groups, or political parties. Id.
Allowing mail ballots to arrive up to fourteen days
after Election Day necessarily means those who must
build their efforts around the operative election rules,
like campaigns and nonpartisan civic groups whose
core activities include election-related work, will
continue their election-monitoring, ballot-chase, and
other operations, with all the economic effort that
entails….

Candidate standing to challenge election rules
that effectively force their campaigns to incur
expenditures, draining resources from other
campaign functions, fits comfortably within this
Court’s long line of cases recognizing standing based
on economic injuries, including by resource diversion.
If a challenged electoral rule tangibly affects the way
a candidate campaigns, by altering in specific,
articulable ways how they spend their limited staff or
volunteer time, money, and resources, it can result in
a concrete injury.

Share this:

“Dole and Kennedy Institutes publish landmark report on funding of election administration”

Release:

A landmark report to be released on June 18 by the Robert J. Dole Institute of Politics and the Edward M. Kennedy Institute for the United States Senate finds that local election administrators consistently lack sustained funding, adequate staffing, and necessary technology at a time of intense public scrutiny and diminished trust in voting results.


The comprehensive anthology report created through the Kennedy and Dole Institutes’ Bolstering Elections Initiative gives election administrators and policymakers the data and research necessary to bolster voting infrastructures at the state and local levels. The report, “Bolstering Funding and Practices for Resilient Elections: Sustainable Funding and Models of Success at the State and Local Level,” was made possible by a grant from the Election Trust Initiative.


“Now, more than ever, the story of the election professionals who conduct our elections, often on a shoestring budget, needs our attention,” said Tammy Patrick, senior advisor to the Bolstering Elections Initiative. “Administrators in cities and in rural areas; in red states, blue states and swing states; those who were elected, appointed, or hired as a public servant; Republicans, Democrats, and unaffiliated officials; all are better able to serve their voters and communities when they are sufficiently supported with the tools and resources the American Voters deserve. Election administration should not be a partisan issue.”

Full report with some top folks in the field contributing.

Share this:

Campaign Finance Issues in the Roman Republic

I’ve been reading Lawless Republic: The Rise of Cicero and the Decline of Rome, by Josiah Osgood. I came across this striking passage on campaign finance issues in elections in 66 BCE, which shows that some of the same issues that affect campaign finance issues today have been around for more than 2,000 years.

As you can see, the Romans struggled over how to define the law between legitimate campaign finance activity and bribery. They also worried that defining bribery too expansively would lead to the weaponization of campaign finance laws. Plus ça change…:

Share this:

“Democrats Get Lowest Rating From Voters in 35 Years, WSJ Poll Finds”

This is from the WSJ, which is paywalled. To put this in a broader perspective, the combined “favorability” of both parties is -41% (Rs at -11%, Ds at -30%), which is the worst combined ratings for the two parties since this poll began in 1990.

This is consistent with the general, precipitous decline in support for the traditionally dominant center-right and center-left parties throughout Europe. I have a good deal to say about that in the 2025 John S. Sullivan Lecture I delivered at Capital University, titled The Decline of Political Authority:  Legal and Political Challenges in Western Democracies, 2015-2025. I’ll be posting that soon.

From the WSJ article:

The Democratic Party’s image has eroded to its lowest point in more than three decades, according to a new Wall Street Journal poll, with voters seeing Republicans as better at handling most issues that decide elections.

The new survey finds that 63% of voters hold an unfavorable view of the Democratic Party—the highest share in Journal polls dating to 1990 and 30 percentage points higher than the 33% who hold a favorable view.

Democrats have been hoping that a voter backlash against the president will be powerful enough to restore their majority in the House in next year’s midterm elections, much as it did during Trump’s first term. But the Journal poll shows that the party hasn’t yet accomplished a needed first step in that plan: persuading voters they can do a better job than Trump’s party….

“The Democratic brand is so bad that they don’t have the credibility to be a critic of Trump or the Republican Party,” said John Anzalone, a Democratic pollster who worked on the Journal survey with Republican Tony Fabrizio. “Until they reconnect with real voters and working people on who they’re for and what their economic message is, they’re going to have problems.”

The only issues on which voters prefer congressional Democrats to Republicans, among the 10 tested in the Journal survey, are healthcare and vaccine policy.

“The Democratic brand is so bad that they don’t have the credibility to be a critic of Trump or the Republican Party,” said John Anzalone, a Democratic pollster who worked on the Journal survey with Republican Tony Fabrizio. “Until they reconnect with real voters and working people on who they’re for and what their economic message is, they’re going to have problems.”…

Because anger is a stronger motivator to vote than satisfaction, the angry town-hall gatherings suggested to many Democrats that the next election could look something like Trump’s first midterm, in 2018, when Republicans lost at least 40 House seats and their majority in the chamber, restoring Democratic Rep. Nancy Pelosi to the speaker’s office. …

But the new Journal survey shows that the political environment today looks different now than in Trump’s first term.

At about this point in 2017, more voters called themselves Democrats than Republicans by 6 percentage points in Journal polling. The Democratic tilt meant that many Republicans, in a sense, were running uphill even before they started, depending on the makeup of their House district….

Now, more voters identify as Republicans than as Democrats, a significant change in the structure of the electorate—and a rarity in politics. Republicans last year built their first durable lead in more than three decades in party identification, and they have maintained that lead today. In the new Journal survey, more voters identify as Republicans than as Democrats by 1 percentage point, and the GOP led by 4 points in the April poll.

Share this:

What’s Going on with the Re-Argument Order in the Louisiana Voting Rights Act Case?

It’s been nearly a month since the Court announced it would hear re-argument in this case and would issue a supplemental order with additional questions to be briefed. That’s a surprisingly long delay.

The Court rarely orders cases to be re-argued, particularly outside the context in which the Court has only eight Justices at the time the case is argued initially, is internally divided 4-4, and orders re-argument once a ninth Justice is on board (those re-arguments typically happen within the same Term in which the case was first heard). In Citizens United, the Court’s re-argument order included the additional questions to be argued. That order came down at the end of June of that Term. In Kiobel v. Royal Dutch Petroleum Co., the Court ordered re-argument six days after the original argument and specified the additional issue to be briefed.

To speculate, perhaps the Court is going to introduce several questions to be argued and the Justices are going back and forth on how exactly to frame those various questions. I’ve also wondered about whether one or more Justices might be writing a dissent from the re-argument order. I’m not sure if that’s ever happened. I’ve also thought about whether the Court could be holding the re-argument order until it gets the cert. papers in the Turtle Mountain Band case on whether Sec. 2 of the VRA creates a private right of action, but that doesn’t seem too likely. But it’s a bit mysterious as to why the re-argument order has not come down yet.

Share this:

Small Donors Fuel the Left of the Democratic Party

This WSJ article confirms what I have been saying for a while now (see also here), that small donors tend to fuel the more ideological wings of the parties. That’s all the more true for out of state (or out of district) small donors. There’s nothing wrong with that. The policy issue is whether public financing of elections should be based on the preferences of small donors, such as in proposals to provide public matching funds in proportion to the amount of small donations a candidate raises.

From the WSJ piece:

The contrast between the two women highlights how Democratic small-dollar donors, an increasingly important group as more fundraising moves online, often are biased in their support of ideological favorites rather than focusing on just those in competitive races.

Among the 10 incumbent Democrats who raised the most from individual donors this year, six are members of the Congressional Progressive Caucus, a Wall Street Journal analysis of campaign finance disclosures shows. Three of the top four are progressives, with the exception of House Minority Leader Hakeem Jeffries (D., N.Y.).

The financial strength among progressives presents a challenge to party leaders trying to nudge the Democratic message closer to the middle, where they might stand a better chance of winning over independent voters who decide close elections….

John Lapp, executive director of the Democratic Congressional Campaign Committee in 2006 when the party won control of the House, said it is often the case that “more provocative stars in the Democratic Party” raise the most money….

Like AOC, Mamdani is a study in the power of small-dollar donations. While his average contribution has been the smallest of any of the mayoral candidates, according to New York City Campaign Finance Board data, he has still managed to be competitive in fundraising because he has had so many more donors than others.

In a sign of Mamdani’s growing national prominence among progressives, roughly half of the dollars he raised during the period came from outside New York City. His campaign had roughly $2.5 million on hand as of July 11….

The fundraising success for progressive candidates comes as traditional depositories for dollars in the party are struggling with their fundraising.

The Republican National Committee, benefiting from GOP control of Washington, had almost $81 million in cash reserves as it started July, compared with $15 million for the Democratic National Committee. Overall, the DNC raised roughly 20% less than it did in the first six months of 2021, a comparable period in the election cycle, and has in the bank a quarter of what it did four years ago….

Some Democratic committees are working to try to keep small-dollar donors focused on the races that matter the most.

Share this:

A quick redistricting thought: the idea of a “dormant” Election Clause

Since Rucho, it’s been generally assumed that attempting to litigate against partisan gerrymanders in federal court is an utter nonstarter. I think this is largely correct, but it light of all the recent discussion over the efforts to make the Texas map even more tilted towards Republicans, it is worth speculating a bit whether there are any plausible arguments remaining after Rucho purported to slam the federal courthouse door shut.

One idea that I’ve written about in at least a couple of pre-Ruch law review articles (The Gerrymander and the Constitution and Constitutional Preservation and Judicial Review of Partisan Gerrymanders), and which was not considered–and thus not rejected–in Rucho, is the idea of a “dormant” Elections Clause analogous to the “dormant” Commerce Clause. The Election Clause of Article I, section 4, lends itself to this kind of “dormant” jurisprudence insofar as it explicitly gives Congress the power to override state laws regulating the procedures of congressional elections. Congress thus needs to retain the ultimate authority over these procedures, just like Congress needs to retain ultimate regulatory power over interstate commerce. But the theory of the “dormant” Commerce Clause is that the federal judiciary can aid Congress in the exercise of its ultimate constitutional authority if it sees state laws that appear fundamentally at odds with the purpose of the constitutional clause. If the judiciary errs in this respect, Congress can correct that error.

This same theory could, and should, apply to the Elections Clause. If a state legislature regulates congressional elections that appear fundamentally at odds with the basic purpose of having the federal House of Representatives chosen “by the people of the several States,” then the federal judiciary could nullify that state law subject to ultimate oversight by Congress itself. The advantage of this “dormant” Election Clause approach, in contrast to the constitutional claims argued in Rucho, is that it does not give the judiciary the last word on congressional redistricting.

While I’m not holding my breath waiting for the Roberts Court to embrace this “dormant” Election Clause theory, it’s at least worth noting that it would avoid what appears to be Chief Justice Roberts’s main concern in his opinion for the Court in Rucho, namely a constitutional doctrine that would put the federal courts in charge of congressional redistricting. Maybe there is at least some small chance that five justices on the current Court would see the whole Madisonian system so out-of-kilter currently, that they would attempt to restore so equilibrium by exercising a “dormant” Election Clause jurisprudence over extreme partisan gerrymanders, subject to the supervision of Congress to approve whatever congressional maps it wishes.

Share this:

Condorcet Voting and the Cornyn-Paxton Race

A new Common Ground Democracy post with this subtitle: “The upcoming U.S. Senate election in Texas perfectly illustrates the importance of this voting reform.” The post itself begins:

“The University of Chicago’s Center for Effective Government, as part of its “Democratic Reform Primer Series,” has published an introductory explanation of Condorcet Voting co-authored by Eric Maskin and me. I’m honored to continue my collaboration with Eric with this piece and to have it included in this valuable collection of papers.

To understand why publication of this explainer on Condorcet Voting is especially timely right now, look no further than the looming U.S. Senate race in Texas.”

The post concludes:

“I will also be discussing the history of Condorcet Voting and its continuing relevance in a lecture at the University of Melbourne next week. When a video of that lecture is available, I will post it.”

Share this:

The Impoundment Act, Polarization, Bipartisanship, and the Budget

The Impoundment Act of 1974 was passed with strong bipartisan support in the pre-polarization era. It was designed to reassert congressional control over the budget, while ac acknowledging there might be circumstances in which Presidents had good reasons not to spend money Congress had appropriated. The President can propose funding that he wants to rescind; Congress then has a fixed time period in which it can either approve or fail to approve the President’s request.

In the pre-polarization era, Congress no doubt assumed that Congress would exert independent judgment about any rescission request and that there would be some degree of bipartisan judgment about whether to approve or reject such a request. But we have now seen in the era of polarization and unified government that one party can approve a rescission request from the same party President. And one fallout from this might be that it will make putting together bipartisan deals to pass an actual budget that much harder. With unified government and polarized parties, rescission become like a line-item presidential veto over spending. If any rescission request by a President of the same party as the party that controls the House and Senate will be approved, that is the practical effect.

That would destabilize bipartisan deals over the budget. If one party can unwind that deal during unified government, the other party cannot have confidence the terms of the deal will stick. This would be an ironic, unintended consequence of legislation enacted in a non-polarized era, designed to reassert congressional control over the executive, that is now being applied in our polarized era.

Share this:

“Will Wisconsin Get New Congressional Maps?”

This piece comments on the new lawsuit challenging Wisconsin’s congressional map on the ground that it’s an anti-competitive (not a partisan) gerrymander that artificially suppresses competition in most districts. HLS’s Election Law Clinic is working with Law Forward to represent the plaintiffs in this case.

The third complaint was filed with the Dane County circuit court shortly after the first two were rejected. For reasons I’ll discuss below, this latest case makes arguments which may bear more fruit for those seeking new maps. . . .

The third court case couples its new arguments with an alternative legal strategy. Wisconsin Business Leaders for Democracy vs WEC was filed on July 8th by several firms, including Law Forward, who brought the successful challenge to the state legislative maps in 2023. Unlike the two previous petitions, it was filed not under the Supreme Court’s original jurisdiction, but as a lawsuit in Dane County circuit court.

The complaint alleges that the existing boundaries are indeed unconstitutional due to gerrymandering, but not, as Bothfield claimed, partisan gerrymandering. Instead, the complaint argues that the map is an anti-competitive gerrymander because it “was intentionally designed to create districts that protected the incumbent members of Wisconsin’s delegation in the U.S. House of Representatives.”

The argument is not that the existing map benefits Republicans over Democrats, but that it was drawn by incumbents to protect themselves from future challengers (of either party). “An anti-competitive gerrymander occurs when elected officials work in concert to draw district lines to suppress electoral competition, thereby benefiting incumbent politicians to the detriment of voters.”

Specifically, the plaintiffs argue that such anti-competitive gerrymanders violate the Wisconsin Constitution’s “guarantees of equal protection to all citizens, the promise to maintain a free government, and the right to vote.” The complaint recognizes that no Wisconsin court has previously recognized such a claim, so they propose a new two-part test. “Under this approach, an unconstitutional anti-competitive gerrymander exists where there is evidence (1) of an intent to suppress competition, and (2) that competition was indeed suppressed relative to alternative maps that satisfy all applicable legal requirements.”

In this way, the Wisconsin Business Leaders for Democracy complaint seeks to offer the courts a way to identify and strike down gerrymanders without relying on any particular partisan outcome.

Share this:

Redistricting for National Partisan Fairness

With mid-decade re-redistricting on the horizon in Ohio and Texas, I wanted to re-up this Slate column I wrote with Aaron Goldzimer a few years back. Over the last two elections, the U.S. House has been exceptionally fair, in aggregate. As Eric McGhee, Chris Warshaw, and I recently documented, the House’s overall efficiency gap was close to zero in both the 2022 and 2024 elections. But new Republican gerrymanders in Ohio and Texas would substantially skew House representation. They would push the House from near-perfect partisan fairness to a considerable pro-Republican tilt.

In our 2022 column, Goldzimer and I outlined a strategy that willing states could use to offset these sorts of maneuvers: redistricting for national partisan fairness. The basic idea is that states would add a new line-drawing criterion: aiming through their congressional maps to achieve, to the extent possible, an unbiased U.S. House in aggregate. Here’s some of the key discussion from our column:

If existing state reforms are counterproductive, and if the federal government has consigned itself to the sidelines, how can a House that accurately reflects the will of the people be achieved? One promising idea is for blue states to require their congressional maps to promote national partisan fairness to the extent possible. There exist several statistical measures of maps’ partisan fairness. These metrics could be applied to the House as a whole rather than to any individual map. Blue states could then design their districts with the aim of minimizing the bias of the House in its entirety.

In practice, this would mean one of three things. If the House as a whole is reasonably balanced, blue states would draw fair maps. If the House is skewed in Democrats’ favor (as it was in the 1970s and 1980s), blue states would craft pro-Republican maps. And if the House has a pro-Republican tilt (as over the last decade), blue states would redistrict to benefit Democrats.

This proposal raises a tricky issue of timing. When blue states design their districts, it might not yet be clear in which direction (if any) the entire House will be biased. One solution is for blue states to wait as long as possible before finalizing their maps. At present, for example, nearly every state is done with congressional redistricting, so the cake is almost baked. Another option is for blue states to endorse three maps: one that’s fair, another that’s pro-Republican, and one more that’s pro-Democratic. The skew of the whole House, when it’s finally known, would then determine which map goes into effect. . . .

This idea is potent enough that if just a few more blue states were persuaded, an unbiased House would actually be attained. Notably, California, Colorado, and Washington are all blue states whose independent commissions are barred from considering partisanship. If instead those commissions were instructed to pursue national partisan fairness—for instance, through voter initiatives taking effect later this decade—the commissions are responsible for enough districts that a fair House would, in fact, be the result.

After we wrote our piece, Goldzimer and James Piltch put together a longer academic version of this proposal. See here for their article, “Recovering from Rucho: How States Can Create National Partisan Fairness.” Interestingly, Gavin Newsom suggested just yesterday that California may try to redraw its congressional map if Texas goes down the road of mid-decade re-redistricting. Legally, this would likely require a constitutional amendment. In policy terms, though, the move would be perfectly defensible as an effort to maintain national partisan fairness.

Share this: